Utility functions on indivisible goods

Some branches of economics and game theory deal with indivisible goods – discrete items that can be traded only as a whole. For example, in combinatorial auctions there is a finite set of items, and every agent can buy a subset of the items, but an item cannot be divided between two or more agents.

It is usually assumed that every agent assigns subjective utility to every subset of the items. This can be represented by one of two ways:

A cardinal utility function implies a preference relation: implies and implies .

Utility functions can have several properties.[1]

Monotonicity

Monotonicity means that an agent always (weakly) prefers to have extra items. Formally:

Monotonicity is equivalent to the free disposal assumption: if an agent may always discard unwanted items, then extra items can never decrease the utility.

Additivity

Main article: Additive utility
Additive utility
0
apple 5
hat 7
apple and hat 12

Additivity (also called: linearity or modularity) means that "the whole is equal to the sum of its parts". I.e, the utility of a set of items is the sum of the utilities of each item separately. This property is relevant only for cardinal utility functions. It says that for every set :

In other words, is an additive function.

An equivalent definition is: for all sets and :

An additive utility function is characteristic of independent goods. For example, an apple and a hat are considered independent: the utility a person receives from having an apple is the same whether or not he has a hat, and vice versa. A typical utility function for this case is given at the right.

Submodularity and Supermodularity

Submodular utility
0
apple 5
bread 7
apple and bread 9

Submodularity means that "the whole is not more than the sum of its parts (but may be less)". Formally, for all sets and :

In other words, is a submodular set function.

An equivalent property is Diminishing marginal utility, which means that for every sets and with , and every :[2]

.

A submodular utility function is characteristic of substitute goods. For example, an apple and a bread loaf can be considered substitutes: the utility a person receives from eating an apple is smaller if he has already ate bread (and vice versa), since he is less hungry in that case. A typical utility function for this case is given at the right.

Supermodular utility
0
apple 5
knife 7
apple and knife 15

Supermodularity is the opposite of submodularity: it means that "the whole is not less than the sum of its parts (but may be more)". I.e, if and are sets, then:

In other words, is a supermodular set function.

An equivalent property is Increasing marginal utility, which means that for all sets and with , and every :

.

A supermoduler utility function is characteristic of complementary goods. For example, an apple and a knife can be considered complementary: the utility a person receives from an apple is larger if he already has a knife (and vice versa), since it is easier to eat an apple after cutting it with a knife. A possible utility function for this case is given at the right.

A utility function is additive if and only if it is both supermodular and submodular.

Subadditivity and Superadditivity

Subadditive which is not submodular
0
X or Y or Z 4
X,Y or Y,Z or Z,X 6
X,Y,Z 9

Subadditivity means that for every pair of disjoint sets :

In other words, is a subadditive set function.

Every submodular function is subadditive, but the opposite is not true. For example, assume that there are 3 identical items, X Y and Z, and the utility depends only on their quantity. The table on the right describes a utility function that is subadditive but not submodular, since:


Superadditivity is the opposite of subadditivity and means that for every pair of disjoint sets :

In other words, is a superadditive set function.

Every supermodular function is superadditive.

A utility function is additive if and only if it is both superadditive and subadditive.

Unit demand

Main article: Unit demand
Unit demand utility
0
apple 5
pear 7
apple and pear 7

Unit demand (UD) means that the agent only wants a single good. If the agent gets two or more goods, he uses the one of them that gives him the highest utility, and discards the rest. Formally:

A unit-demand function is an extreme case of a submodular function. It is characteristic of goods that are pure substitutes. For example, if there are an apple and a pear, and an agent wants to eat a single fruit, then his utility function is unit-demand, as exemplified in the table at the right.

Gross substitutes

An illustration of the containment relations between common classes of utility functions.

Gross substitutes (GS) means that the agents regards the items as substitute goods or independent goods but not complementary goods. There are many formal definitions to this property, all of which are equivalent.

See Gross substitutes (indivisible items) for more details.

Hence the following relations hold between the classes:

See diagram on the right.

Aggregates of utility functions

A utility function describes the happiness of an individual. Often, we need a function that describes the happiness of an entire society. Such a function is called a Social welfare function, and it is usually an aggregate function of two or more utility functions. If the individual utility functions are additive, then the following is true for the aggregate functions:

Aggregate function Property Example[4]
f g h aggregate(f,g,h)
Sum Additive 1,3; 4 3,1; 4 4,4; 8
Average Additive 1,3; 4 3,1; 4 2,2; 4
Minimum Super-additive 1,3; 4 3,1; 4 1,1; 4
Maximum Sub-additive 1,3; 4 3,1; 4 3,3; 4
Median neither 1,3; 4 3,1; 4 1,1; 2 1,1; 4
1,3; 4 3,1; 4 3,3; 6 3,3; 4

See also

References

  1. Gul, F.; Stacchetti, E. (1999). "Walrasian Equilibrium with Gross Substitutes". Journal of Economic Theory. 87: 95. doi:10.1006/jeth.1999.2531.
  2. Moulin, Hervé (1991). Axioms of cooperative decision making. Cambridge England New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521424585.
  3. Koopmans, T. C.; Beckmann, M. (1957). "Assignment Problems and the Location of Economic Activities". Econometrica. 25: 53. doi:10.2307/1907742. JSTOR 1907742.
  4. values of functions on {a}, {b} and {a,b}.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 10/14/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.