Stylized fact

In social sciences, especially economics, a stylized fact is a simplified presentation of an empirical finding.[1] A stylized fact is often a broad generalization that summarizes some complicated statistical calculations, which although essentially true may have inaccuracies in the detail.

A prominent example of a stylized fact is: "Education significantly raises lifetime income." Another stylized fact in economics is: "In advanced economies, real GDP growth fluctuates in a recurrent but irregular fashion".

As noted above, scrutiny to detail will often produce counterexamples. In the case given above, holding a PhD may lower lifetime income, because of the years of lost earnings it implies and because many PhD holders enter academia instead of higher-paid fields. Nonetheless, broadly speaking, people with more education tend to earn more, so the above example is true in the sense of a stylized fact.

Origin of the term

For more details on this topic, see Kaldor's facts.

The term “stylised facts” was introduced by the economist Nicholas Kaldor in the context of a debate on economic growth theory in 1961,[2] expanding on model assumptions made in a 1957 paper.[3] Criticizing the neoclassical models of economic growth of his time, Kaldor argues that theory construction should begin with a summary of the relevant facts. However, to handle the problem that “facts as recorded by statisticians, are always subject to numerous snags and qualifications, and for that reason are incapable of being summarized”,[4] he suggests that theorists “should be free to start off with a stylised view of the facts – i.e. concentrate on broad tendencies, ignoring individual detail”.[4] With respect to broad tendencies that result from such a process, Kaldor coins the term “stylized facts”.

Examples

Stylized facts are widely used in economics, in particular to motivate the construction of a model and/or to validate it. Examples are:

Uses

Already in the original paper, Kaldor used his stylized facts of economic growth to argue in favor of his suggested model in comparison to older neoclassical models of economic growth. This idea has been highlighted subsequently by Boland, that the advantages of one model over the other can be set in a clear perspective via the reference of the stylized facts the respective models can explain.[6] Additionally, stylized facts can be used to look "under the hood of models", i.e. be used to validate assumptions of model in a focused way.[7] This can be of particular importance in more complex models. Econophysics/Statistical finance begins from stylized facts. Furthermore, the considerable potential of Stylized Facts for Information Systems research has been investigated and discussed in recent years.[8]

Criticism and derivation of stylized facts

Already in an early response Solow pinpointed a possible problem of stylized facts, by stating that there "is no doubt that they are stylized, though it is possible to question whether they are facts."[9] The criticized practice of deriving stylized facts ad hoc is still quite prevalent in economics. Still, some possible approaches to derive stylized facts from empirical evidence have been suggested, such as surveying experts, statistically analysing large data sets (especially suitable for financial markets[10]) or aggregating both qualitative and quantitative data from different empirical methods by following a systematic process.[7]

References

  1. Thomas Cooley, ed., (1995): Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, page 3. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0-691-04323-X.
  2. Nicholas Kaldor (1961), 'Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth.' In: Lutz/Hague (eds.): The Theory of Capital, London, pp. 177-222.
  3. Nicholas Kaldor (1957), 'A model of economic growth.' The Economic Journal 67 (268), pp. 591-624.
  4. 1 2 Kaldor 1961, p. 178
  5. Kahn, James A. (1987). "Inventories and the Volatility of Production". American Economic Review. 77 (4): 667–679. JSTOR 1814538.
  6. Boland (1987). "Stylized Facts". In Eatwell, J.; Milgate, M.; Newman, P. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. 4. London: Macmillan Press. pp. 535–536. ISBN 0-333-37235-2.
  7. 1 2 Heine, Bernd-O.; Meyer, Matthias; Strangfeld, Oliver (2005). "Stylised Facts and the Contribution of Simulation to the Economic Analysis of Budgeting". Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation. 8 (4): 4.
  8. Houy, Constantin; Fettke, Peter; Loos, Peter (2015). "Stylized Facts as an Instrument for Literature Review and Cumulative Information Systems Research.". Communications of the AIS (CAIS). 37 (1): 225–256.
  9. Solow (1969). Growth Theory: an Exposition (Paperback ed.). New York, NY: Oxford Univ. Press. p. 2.
  10. Cont, R. (2001). "Empirical Properties of Asset Returns: Stylized Facts and Statistical Issues". Quantitative Finance. 1 (2): 223–236. doi:10.1080/713665670.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 7/5/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.