Inclusionary zoning

Inclusionary zoning(IZ), also known as inclusionary housing, is an American term which refers to municipal and county planning ordinances that require a given share of new construction to be affordable by people with low to moderate incomes. The term inclusionary zoning indicates that these ordinances seek to counter exclusionary zoning practices, which aim to exclude low-cost housing from a municipality through the zoning code. There are variations among different inclusionary zoning programs, firstly, they could be mandatory or voluntary.[1] They are also variations among the set-aside requirements, affordability levels coupled with the period of control.[1] In order to encourage engagements in these zoning programs, developers are awarded with incentives for engaging in these programs, such as density bonus, expedited approval and fee waivers.[1]

In practice, these policies involve placing deed restrictions on 10–30% of new houses or apartments in order to make the cost of the housing affordable to lower-income households. The mix of "affordable housing" and "market-rate" housing in the same neighborhood is seen as beneficial by city planners and sociologists.[2] Inclusionary zoning is a tool for local municipalities in the United States to allegedly help provide a wider range of housing options than a free market provides on its own. Many economists consider the program as a price control on a percentage of units, which negatively impacts the supply of housing.[3]

Most inclusionary zoning is enacted at the municipal or county level; when imposed by the state, as in Massachusetts, it has been argued that such laws usurp local control. In such cases, developers can use inclusionary zoning to avoid certain aspects of local zoning laws.

Historical background

During the mid- to late-20th century, new suburbs grew and expanded around American cities as middle-class house buyers, supported by federal loan programs such as Veterans Administration housing loan guarantees, left established neighborhoods and communities. These newly populated places were generally more economically homogeneous than the cities they encircled. Many suburban communities enacted local ordinances, often in zoning codes, to preserve the character of their municipality. One of the most commonly cited exclusionary practices is the stipulation that lots must be of a certain minimum size and houses must be set back from the street a certain minimum distance. In many cases, these housing ordinances prevented affordable housing from being built, because the large plots of land required to build within the code restrictions were cost-prohibitive for modestly priced houses. Communities have remained accessible to wealthier citizens because of these ordinances, effectively shutting the low income families out of desirable communities. Such zoning ordinances have not always been enacted with conscious intent to exclude lower income households, but it has been the unintended result of such policies.

By denying lower income families access to suburban communities, many feel that exclusionary zoning has contributed to the maintenance of inner city ghettos. Supporters of inclusionary zoning point out that low income households are more likely to become economically successful if they have middle class neighbors as peers and role models. When effective, inclusionary zoning reduces the concentration of poverty in slum districts where social norms may not provide adequate models of success. Education is one of the largest components in the effort to lift people out of poverty; access to high-quality public schools is another key benefit of reduced segregation. Statistically, a poor child in a school where 80% of the children are poor scores 13-15% lower compared to environments where the poor child's peers are 80% middle class.[4]

In many of the communities where inclusionary zoning has been put into practice, income requirements allow households that earn 80-120% of the median income to qualify for the "affordable" housing. This is because in many places high housing prices have prevented even median-income households from buying market-rate properties. This is especially prominent in California, where only 16% of the population could afford the median-priced home during 2005.[5]

Potential benefits and limitations of IZ Policies

Potential benefits

Potential limitations

Differences in ordinances

Inclusionary zoning ordinances vary substantially among municipalities. These variables can include:

Alternative solutions

While many suburban communities feature Section 8 for low income households, they are generally restricted to concentrated sections. In some cases, counties specify small districts where Section 8 properties are to be rented. In other cases, the market tends to self-segregate property by income. For instance, in Montgomery County, Pennsylvania, a wealthy suburban county bordering Philadelphia, only 5% of the county's population live in the borough of Norristown, yet 50% of the county's Section 8 properties are located there.[10] The large low income resident population burdens Norristown's local government and school district, while much of the county remains unburdened.

Inclusionary zoning aims to reduce residential economic segregation by mandating that a mix of incomes be represented in a single development.

Controversy

Inclusionary zoning remains a controversial issue. Some affordable housing advocates seek to promote the policies in order to ensure that housing is available for a variety of income levels in more places. These supporters hold that inclusionary zoning produces needed affordable housing and creates income-integrated communities.

Yet other Affordable Housing advocates state the reverse is true, that Inclusionary Zoning can have the opposite effect and actually reduce affordable housing in a community. For example, in Los Angeles, California, inclusionary zoning apparently accelerated gentrification, as older, unprofitable buildings were razed and replaced with mostly high-rent housing, and a small percentage of affordable housing; the net result was less affordable housing. In New York, NY, inclusionary zoning allows for up to a 400% increase in luxury housing for every unit of affordable housing and for an additional 400% luxury housing when combined with the liberal use of development rights. Critics have stated the affordable housing can be directed to those making up to $200,000 through the improper use of an Area Median Income, and used as political tools by organizations tied to various politicians. New York City communities such as Harlem, the Lower East Side, Williamsburg, Chelsea and Hell's Kitchen have experienced significant secondary displacement through the use of Inclusionary Zoning.

Real Estate industry detractors note that inclusionary zoning levies an indirect tax on developers, so as to discourage them from building in areas that face supply shortages. Furthermore, to ensure that the affordable units are not resold for profit, deed restrictions generally fix a long-term resale price ceiling, eliminating a potential benefit of home ownership.

Free market advocates oppose attempts to fix given social outcomes by government intervention in markets. They argue inclusionary zoning constitutes an onerous land use regulation that exacerbates housing shortages.

Homeowners sometimes note that their property values will be reduced if low income families move into their community. Others counter consider their concerns thinly-concealed classism and racism.

Some of the most widely publicized inclusionary zoning battles have involved the REIT AvalonBay Communities. According to the company's website, AvalonBay seeks to develop properties in "high barrier-to-entry markets" across the United States. In practice, AvalonBay uses inclusionary zoning laws, such as the Massachusetts Comprehensive Permit Act: Chapter 40B, to bypass local zoning laws and build large apartment complexes. In some cases, local residents fight back with a lawsuit. In Connecticut, similar developments by AvalonBay have resulted in attempts to condemn the land or reclaim it by eminent domain.[11] In most cases AvalonBay has won these disputes and built extremely profitable apartments or condominiums.

Other legal battles have occurred in California, where many cities have implemented inclusionary zoning policies that typically require 10 percent to 15 percent of units to be affordable housing.[12] The definition of affordable housing includes both low-income housing and moderate-income housing. In California, low-income housing is typically designed for households making 51 percent to 80 percent of the median income, and moderate-income housing is typically for households making 81 percent to 120 percent of the median income.[12] Developers have attempted to fight back these requirements by challenging local inclusionary zoning ordinances through the court legal system. In the case Home Builders Association of Northern California v. City of Napa, the California First District Court of Appeal upheld the inclusionary zoning ordinances of City of Napa that require 10 percent of units of the new development project to be moderate income housing against the Home Builders Association that challenged the City of Napa.[13] Cities have also attempted to impose inclusionary requirements on rental units. However, the Costa-Hawkins Rental Housing Act prohibits cities in California from imposing limitation on rental rates on vacant units.[14] Subsequently developers have won cases, such as Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, L.P. v. City of Los Angeles (2009), against cities that imposed inclusionary requirements on rental units, as the state law supersedes local ordinances.[15]

Citizen groups and developers have also sought other ways to strengthen or defeat inclusionary zoning laws. For example, the initiative and referendum process in California allows citizen groups or developers to change local ordinances on affordable housing by popular vote. Any citizens or interest groups can participate in this process by gathering at least the required number of signatures so that the measure proposed can quality to be on the ballot; once enough signatures are submitted and the ballot measure is cleared by election officials, the ballot measure is typically placed on the ballot for the upcoming election.[16] One recent case is Proposition C in San Francisco. This ballot measure was placed on the ballot for the June 2016 California primary election. Passed in June 2016, this proposition amends the City's Charter to increase the requirement for affordable housing for development projects of 25 units or more.[17]

The clash between these various interests is reflected in this study published by the libertarian-leaning Reason Foundation's public policy think tank, and the response of a peer review of that research. Local governments reflect and in some cases balance these competing interests. In California, the League of Cities has created a guide to inclusionary zoning which includes a section on the pros and cons of the policies.

Failure in improving social integration coupled with increasing social cost

It is suggested that IZ policies may not effectively disperse low-income units throughout the region, which actually contradicts the aim of the policy itself.[18] For instances in Suffolk County, it is found that there is a spatial concentration of IZ units in poor neighbourhood coupled with higher proportions of Black and Hispanic, which are considered the minorities.[18] Furthermore, 97.7% of the IZ units were built in only 10% of the census tract from 1980 t0 2000, which is area with the lowest-income neighbourhood coupled with clustering of minorities.[18] It is indispensable to notice that housing policies is controlled by local government rather than regional government in Suffolk County, therefore without regional coordinations of housing policy, it fails to consider the inter-municipality distribution of low-income household within the county.[18] Besides, density bonuses given to property developers for the provision of IZ units have intensified the concentration of affordable units in poor neighborhood (Ryan & Enderle as cited in Mukhija, Das, Regus et al., 2012).[19] This shows that IZ policies may fail to disperse the low-income distributions when it is carried out without taking regional coordination into account.

Moreover, with density bonuses allocated to property developers for the provision of IZ units, it implies the community would be bearing the cost of increasing population density and sharing existing infrastructure.[19]

In practice

More than 200 communities in the United States have some sort of inclusionary zoning provision.[20]

Montgomery County, Maryland, is often held to be a pioneer in establishing inclusionary zoning policies. It is the sixth wealthiest county in the United States, yet it has built more than 10,000 units of affordable housing since 1974, many units door-to-door with market-rate housing.[21]

All municipalities in the state of Massachusetts are subject to that state's General Laws Chapter 40B, which allows developers to bypass certain municipal zoning restrictions in those municipalities which have fewer than the statutorily defined 10% affordable housing units. Developers taking advantage of Chapter 40B must construct 20% affordable units as defined under the statute.[22]

All municipalities in the state of New Jersey are subject to judicially imposed inclusionary zoning as a result of the New Jersey Supreme Court's Mount Laurel Decision and subsequent acts of the New Jersey state legislature.[23]

A 2006 study found that 170 jurisdictions in California had some form of inclusionary housing.[24] This was a 59% increase from 2003, when only 107 jurisdictions had inclusionary housing.[25] In addition, state law requires that 15% of the housing units produced in redevelopment project areas must be affordable. At least 20% of revenue generated from a redevelopment project must be contributed to low-income and moderate-income housing.[12] However, Governor Jerry Brown passed AB 1X 26 that dissolved all redevelopment agencies on February 1, 2012.

However, Los Angeles, California's inclusionary zoning ordinance for rental housing was invalidated in 2009 by the California Court of Appeal for the Second Appellate District because it directly conflicted with a provision of the state's Costa-Hawkins Rental Housing Act of 1996 which specifically gave all landlords the right to set the "initial rental rate" for new housing units.[26]

Madison, Wisconsin's inclusionary zoning ordinance respecting rental housing was struck down by Wisconsin's 4th District Court of Appeals in 2006 because that appellate court construed inclusionary zoning to be rent control, which is prohibited by state statute. The Wisconsin Supreme Court declined the City's request to review the case. The ordinance was structured with a sunset in February 2009, unless extended by the Common Council. The Common Council did not extend the inclusionary zoning ordinance and therefore it expired and is no longer in effect.

Other communities with inclusionary zoning ordinances on the books include:

The trend of going mandatory over voluntary

While inclusionary zoning can be either mandatory or voluntary, some studies have shown that mandatory approaches could be crucial to the success of inclusionary zoning programs in terms of providing a larger number of affordable housing.[44] Below are some examples showing the greater effect of mandatory practice over voluntary practice:[45]

Municipality or County Under voluntary practice Under mandatory practice
Cambridge, MA Cannot generate any affordable housing within 10 years Switching to a mandatory program in 1999, 135 housing units was produced and 58 more were in pipeline as of June 2004.
Irvine, CA Confusion and uncertainty were found under a voluntary program, which motivated developers to initiate a switch to a mandatory ordinance A new mandatory ordinance, which was enforced in 2003 with uniform expectations and rewards for developers,led to the creation of 3,400 affordable housings, with 750 more in the pipeline in June 2004.
Orange County, CA 952 units were produced over eleven years (1983-1994). 6,389 units of affordable housing were produced in four years (1979-1983)

Moreover, the fact that Denver’s mandatory ordinance has contributed to the supply of around 3,400 units of affordable housing, including both constructed one or those in the development pipeline) since the law was passed in 2002, further showcase the greater effect of mandatory programs.

See also

Notes

  1. 1 2 3 Castro, Julián (2013). "Inclusionary Zoning and Mixed-Income Communities". Evidence Matters. Spring 2013 via Office of Policy Development and Research (PD&R) U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development.
  2. Andres Duany et al, "Suburban Nation: The Rise of Sprawl and the Decline of the American Dream" (2000) North Point Press
  3. "The Economics of Inclusionary Zoning Reclaimed: How Effective are Price Controls?" Florida State University Law Review
  4. Gamaliel
  5. CAR
  6. Brown, K. (2001). EXPANDING AFFORDABLE HOUSING THROUGH INCLUSIONARY ZONING: LESSONS FROM THE WASHINGTON METROPOLITAN AREA (1st ed.). The Brookings Institution Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy.
  7. Brunick, N., Goldberg, L., & Levine, S. Large Cities and Inclusionary Zoning (1st ed.). Business and Professional People for the Public Interest.
  8. Calavita, Nico; Mallach, Alan (2010). Inclusionary Housing in International Perspective: Affordable Housing,Social Inclusion, and Land Value Recapture. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
  9. Schwartz, Heather L., Liisa Ecola, Kristin J. Leuschner and Aaron Kofner. Is Inclusionary Zoning Inclusionary? A Guide for Practitioners. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation, 2012. http://www.rand.org/pubs/technical_reports/TR1231.html.
  10. Northeast Times
  11. New York Times
  12. 1 2 3 Fulton, William; Shigley, Paul (2012). Guide to California Planning. Point Arena, CA: Solano Press Books. pp. 221, 305, and 332. ISBN 9781938166020.
  13. "HOME BUILDERS ASSOCIATION OF NORTHERN CALIFORNIA v. CITY OF NAPA". landuselaw.wustl.edu. Retrieved 2016-11-14.
  14. "CA Codes (civ:1954.50-1954.535)". www.leginfo.ca.gov. Retrieved 2016-11-15.
  15. Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, Lp v. City of Los Angeles, July 22, 2009, retrieved 2016-11-15
  16. "Initiative and Referendum Qualification Status | California Secretary of State". www.sos.ca.gov. Retrieved 2016-11-15.
  17. "Final digest-Inclusionary Housing Requirements (Charter Amendment)" (PDF). sfgov.org. City and County of San Francisco, Department of Elections. March 4, 2016. Retrieved 2016-11-14.
  18. 1 2 3 4 E. Kontokosta, Constantine (2015). "Do inclusionary zoning policies equitably disperse affordable housing? A comparative spatial analysis". Journal of Housing and the Built Environment. 30: 569–590 via Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht.
  19. 1 2 Mukhija, Vinit; Das, Ashok; Regus, Lara; Tsay, Sara Slovin (2015-03-15). "The Tradeoffs of Inclusionary Zoning: What Do We Know and What Do We Need to Know?". Planning Practice & Research. 30 (2): 222–235. doi:10.1080/02697459.2015.1008793. ISSN 0269-7459.
  20. North Park
  21. BPI Chicago
  22. SeeMassachusetts Chapter 40B
  23. See New Jersey Fair Housing Act
  24. California rural housing
  25. California rural housing
  26. Palmer/Sixth Street Properties, LP v. City of Los Angeles, 175 Cal. App. 4th 1396 (2009).
  27. Burlington Planning
  28. Cape Cod Commission
  29. Princeton TWP
  30. Frederick Housing Information
  31. Chapel Hill
  32. WCSR
  33. Tallahassee Planning
  34. Boulder Planning
  35. Santa Fe community development
  36. San Francisco government
  37. City of Palo Alto
  38. HLCSMC
  39. LSNC
  40. West Hollywood
  41. Huntington Beach Inclusionary Housing
  42. Montclair
  43. Ziegler, Clark (2002). "Inclusionary Zoning: Lessons Learned in Massachusetts". NHC Affordable Housing Policy Review.
  44. Brunick, Nicholas et al. Voluntary Or Mandatory Inclusionary Housing? Production, Predictability, And Enforcement. 1st ed., Business And Professional People For The Public Interest (BPI), 2004,.

References

External links

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 11/18/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.